A
common argument that is often brought up to argue against free market
capitalism is Korea's economic development. Many argue that despite
the fact that President Park
Chung-hee was a dictator, one thing that people cannot argue
against is the economic
development that Korea enjoyed under his 17-year-long rule.
Specifically,
what those people are usually referring to is the series of
protections, quotas, tariffs, and subsidies that President Park had
given to what were then nascent chaebol companies.
One
such defender of that point of view is Professor Ha-joon
Chang, an economics professor at the
University of Cambridge, and the author of such books as Bad
Samaritans, Kicking
Away The Ladder, and 23
Things They Don't Tell You About Capitalism.
Professor Ha-joon Chang Image Source |
Much
can be said about his books, and I plan to do so in the future. For
now, however, I will focus only on his defense of the
infant industry argument, which is an idea that argues that
emerging businesses and industries require government protection –
in the form of tariffs, subsidies, and quotas – from their more
entrenched competitors, particularly foreign competitors.
In
that article that I linked earlier from The Independent,
Professor Chang compares nascent industries to his six-year-old
child. If this weren't a cringe-worthy moment of stupidity and/or
academic dishonesty, I don't know what is.
Image Source |
Moving
on, in Bad Samaritans, Professor Chang makes the argument that
Korea's economy did not develop because of neo-liberal economic
policies, but rather due to heavy government involvement in the
economy. There is no question that that is true.
There
is also no question that Korea's rapid economic growth was nothing short
of miraculous. There is a reason that it is often referred to as the
Miracle on the Han River. But is that proof that protectionism
was what allowed Korea's economy to develop so quickly? Well, that's
quite hard to confirm considering the fact that Singapore
and Hong
Kong, which practised freer trade policies, went through much
quicker and greater economic development.
“But
they are city-states; they cannot be compared to a country that is so
much bigger like Korea,” I often hear people say.
Fine,
fair enough. Then one has to wonder about China and India. Both
countries are much
bigger than Korea and their economies grew much more quickly after
they began to liberalize their respective economies (see here
and here).
Of
course, this is certainly not to say that government controls and
economic programs are non-existent in Hong Kong or Singapore or China
or India. They are not
free market economies. But they have shown that freer
markets do lead to greater growth.
Image Source |
Another
point that Professor Chang does not mention is that subsidization and
other forms of government protections do not guarantee economic
survival or development in any way, stretch, or form.
Yes,
Korea is an example of an economic success story. However, we also
have to look at other examples where protecting infant industries
were not successful. For example, African
cotton farmers want their governments to end the subsidies programs for their respective national industries so that they can finally compete in the international market; and which African country's economic development could ever compare with
Korea's economic growth?
The
problems of protecting infant industries are not limited to African
countries. In the United States, despite the government's efforts to
prop up Solyndra,
a company that specialized in manufacturing solar cells, with up to
US$535 million of taxpayers' money, the
company still declared bankruptcy.
Similar
examples can be found in Korea, too. Samsung was certainly one of the
chaebol conglomerates that the Korean government helped to protect
and nurture. However, Samsung is not the only business that got so
much love from the government. Another industry that has gotten a
lot of love from the Korean government is the rice industry. So
why has Samsung become an internationally well-known name but there
isn't a single Korean food-producing company that is as well-known
outside of Korea?
In
other words, no amount of subsidies or trade protections ever seems to
be able to prevent what was always doomed to fail from failing.
So
what does Korea owe its economic success to? That is a difficult question to answer; much more difficult than Professor Chang would like for his readers to believe. It's certainly not free market
economics. As Professor Chang has shown, the Korean government
has been heavily involved in Korea's economy. But as I have shown,
freer markets like Hong Kong and Singapore have grown more quickly
than Korea and subsidies do not guarantee success.
Though
that specific question may be harder to answer, what is much easier
to answer is that Korea's economy did not develop because
of
the government's protections, subsidies, and overall involvement in
the economy, but rather in
spite of them.
Image Source |
No comments:
Post a Comment